top of page
Search

Monetary Response: Central Banks' Role in Crisis Recovery

  • Writer: Mark Fernando
    Mark Fernando
  • Jan 31
  • 5 min read

3rd April 2020

Central banks around the world are taking bold actions to combat the economic downturn. What will the long-term effects of these interventions be on inflation, debt, and the global economy?


The year 2020 has witnessed an unprecedented crisis—one that has sent shockwaves through economies across the globe. The economic impact of the COVID-19 pandemic has been swift and severe, throwing many industries into disarray and prompting governments and financial institutions to respond with all the tools at their disposal. Among these tools, central banks have played a crucial role in attempting to stabilise economies and provide liquidity where it’s most needed.


As economies plunged into lockdowns, central banks were quick to lower interest rates and announce various stimulus packages to ease the burden on businesses, households, and financial institutions. The Federal Reserve in the United States, the European Central Bank, and the Bank of England, among others, have all announced large-scale interventions. These actions, while necessary in the short term, raise important questions about the longer-term consequences. What will be the impact on inflation? How will these interventions affect the level of debt in the global economy? And, perhaps most importantly, what will the recovery look like once the crisis has passed?


One could argue that we find ourselves in a scene reminiscent of the opening chapters of Frankenstein, where Victor Frankenstein, in his desperate desire to overcome death, embarks on a path that brings irreversible consequences. Central banks, much like Frankenstein, are operating in a desperate attempt to keep the economic machinery running smoothly. They are acting swiftly to prevent an economic collapse, but the long-term implications of their actions could very well be monstrous.


Central banks have certainly faced a difficult balancing act. On the one hand, they must provide liquidity to prevent a financial crisis from spiralling into a depression. On the other hand, they must be mindful of the long-term risks associated with these interventions. The key question is whether the monetary response to the crisis will lead to an inflationary spiral, as seen in the hyperinflations of the 20th century, or if it will simply lead to an ever-increasing burden of debt.


To answer this, we must first understand the mechanics of central banks' interventions. In essence, central banks have two primary tools at their disposal: interest rate adjustments and quantitative easing (QE). The first involves lowering the cost of borrowing money, thereby encouraging businesses and households to spend and invest. The second, quantitative easing, involves the central bank purchasing financial assets such as government bonds, thereby injecting money directly into the economy.


In a time of crisis, these tools are essential. By lowering interest rates, central banks can make it cheaper for businesses to borrow, encouraging them to maintain operations and continue employing workers. Similarly, by engaging in QE, central banks can ensure that there is sufficient liquidity in the market to support financial institutions and maintain the functioning of credit markets.


However, the success of these measures is not guaranteed. As we have seen in Japan over the past two decades, monetary interventions alone are not enough to spark a sustainable recovery. Even with zero or negative interest rates and massive amounts of QE, Japan has struggled with low inflation and sluggish economic growth. A similar fate may await economies that rely too heavily on monetary intervention without addressing the underlying structural issues that hinder growth.


Moreover, the actions of central banks come with significant risks. The most immediate concern is inflation. By injecting large amounts of money into the economy, central banks risk devaluing currencies and triggering inflationary pressures. While inflation has remained subdued in the years following the 2008 financial crisis, the sheer scale of the current interventions may lead to higher inflation in the coming years. If inflation rises faster than wages, households may experience a real decrease in their purchasing power, leading to a reduction in living standards.


There is also the question of debt. In order to fund the various stimulus packages and bailouts, governments have turned to debt markets, issuing government bonds to raise the necessary funds. While central banks are purchasing these bonds, the amount of government debt in the system is rising at an alarming rate. For many countries, this debt is already unsustainable, and the prospect of ever-increasing levels of debt may pose serious challenges in the future. At some point, the costs of servicing this debt could outweigh the benefits of the interventions, leading to higher taxes, austerity measures, or even defaults.


Yet, it would be foolish to disregard the potential benefits of these interventions. In times of crisis, the role of central banks is to act as a stabilising force. They are the ones who step in when markets falter, ensuring that there is enough liquidity to keep the wheels of the economy turning. Without these interventions, it is likely that the global economy would face a far worse fate.


The reality, however, is that the road to recovery will not be smooth. As central banks continue to inject money into the economy, they must remain vigilant of the longer-term consequences. If inflation begins to rise, central banks may be forced to raise interest rates, which could slow the recovery and potentially lead to another recession. Similarly, if government debt continues to rise, it may lead to fiscal crises that could destabilise entire economies.


In this sense, we are once again reminded of The Great Gatsby by F. Scott Fitzgerald. Just as Gatsby’s lavish parties were built on the illusion of wealth, the economic recovery built on the back of central bank interventions may also prove to be an illusion. The question is whether central banks can navigate the delicate balance between short-term intervention and long-term stability. Only time will tell if their actions will prove to be a temporary fix or a sustainable solution.


The recovery from this crisis will depend on a variety of factors, and while central banks will play a crucial role in the short term, it is likely that the real solutions will come from structural reforms in the economy. These reforms must address the underlying issues that have led to stagnation and inequality in many advanced economies. Until then, the central banks will continue to play a leading role in the recovery process, but the ultimate success of their efforts remains uncertain.


In conclusion, while central banks’ interventions have been necessary to stabilise the global economy, their long-term impact remains unclear. The potential risks of inflation and rising debt levels must be carefully managed, and the eventual path to recovery may require a combination of monetary policy, fiscal reform, and structural change. Just as in The Picture of Dorian Gray, where the pursuit of beauty leads to eventual ruin, the pursuit of economic stability through monetary intervention may have unforeseen consequences. Only time will tell whether central banks have successfully navigated the treacherous waters of crisis recovery, or whether their efforts will be seen as a temporary reprieve in a much larger, more complex struggle.

 
 
bottom of page